Arbitration avoidance is in full swing as we enter the month of February. Forty-four players have exchanged salary figures with their clubs. Of those, all but 18 have reached deals avoiding arbitration, which begins in approximately two weeks. Most of the remaining 18 will also reach deals. Perhaps a handful will proceed to arbitration. This year’s most interesting case is Tim Lincecum, a Super Two player who is set to go to his arbitration hearing armed with two Cy Young awards. The gap between the salary Lincecum is seeking ($13 million) and what the Giants have submitted ($8 million) is the largest for any player this year. It’s worth wondering, as a sharp reader did during my first BP chat, how teams and players come up with the numbers they exchange.
Tug of War or Rubber Band?
There are two forces that shape both parties’ decisions in the arbitration process. First, teams and players recognize that most cases settle before reaching arbitration, and that most cases settle at or near the midpoint between the player figure and the team figure. However, the two sides also must grapple with the small but real possibility that they do not reach a deal and the case goes before a three-person arbitration panel. Although the percentage of cases that proceed to a hearing is small (just three of the 45 non-free-agent cases in 2009), the structure of the arbitration process looms large. It is unclear whether there are any general trends that dictate which cases go all the way to arbitration (for example, whether such cases adhere to the Priest-Klein selection hypothesis), although this remains a question of interest for me.
The vast majority of arbitration-eligible players agree to deals that avoid hearings. Often, hearings create bad feelings that carry over into the season. Furthermore, the process is expensive and time-consuming. For both sides involved in the process, it is usually easiest to agree to a deal that is exactly at the midpoint. For example, in 2009, the (unweighted) average settlement was 46 percent of the difference between the two numbers. In other words, the average settlement was very close to the midpoint, and it slightly favored teams. So far this year, the corresponding figure has been 44 percent, perhaps reflecting weaker overall demand. Nevertheless, by far the most common single settlement percentage is 50 percent. Here is a simple table showing the settlement percentages for 2009. Zero represents the team figure and 100-percent represents the player figure:
Percentage Cases of Difference Settled 0-25 2 26-35 3 36-45 6 46-55 16 56-65 3 66-75 0 76-100 1
Here is a similar table for this year:
Percentage Cases of Difference Settled 0-25 0 26-35 1 36-45 9 46-55 6 56-65 0 66-75 0 76-100 0
Note again here that the distribution appears to favor teams ever so slightly. This is a somewhat odd result that we shall return to later. However, suffice it to say that most of the cases cluster near the midpoint of the two figures.
Incentives to Cheat
This phenomenon gives teams and players a peculiar set of incentives. If, by striking deals at the easy focal point of 50 percent, parties hope to save time and money, they had better hope that the practice doesn’t distort incentives. But the possibility exists for it to do just that. For every dollar a team reduces its figure by, the anticipated settlement price declines by fifty cents. Similarly, for each dollar a player increases his figure, his anticipated salary increases by fifty cents.
This set of incentives, if teams and players always settled at the midpoint, would be unstable. Teams would simply offer zero dollars and players would submit exorbitant figures. Of course, this doesn’t happen in reality because the parties to the dispute are conscious of the possibility that they will go all the way to the hearing, which is binding. Because of the unique nature of baseball’s arbitration rules, the arbitrators may not select any salary figure they like, but rather they must choose either the player figure or the team figure. That is to say, it’s an all-or-nothing affair.
What incentives does this create? In fact, it creates exactly the opposite set of incentives from the ones created by the midpoint settlement norm. Each dollar that a club reduces its offer by increases the likelihood that an arbitrator will select its figure. Because the outcome at arbitration is binary, that likelihood is crucial. If one party can appear ever so slightly more reasonable than the other, it wins the whole pie. Of course, the other party seeks to appear yet more reasonable. In essence, the fact that the parties bargain in the shadow of the law means that they are forced toward the middle of the settlement range.
These two forces work against each other. The first, the fact that parties tend to settle at or near the midpoint of the settlement range, pushes their salary figures apart. The second, the structure of baseball’s arbitration hearings, pushes the parties back together. However, in individual cases, the parties may miscalculate. If one party is willing to submit a figure very close to the expected salary for the player and the other does not, the party close to expected value may insist on proceeding all the way to a hearing. In that case, the party far from the midpoint may end up holding the bag. I suspect this is what happened with Lincecum. Although his $13-million filing was a record for a player in his first year of eligibility, it is perhaps closer to what he could expect to earn than the number submitted by the Giants. If that is the case, Lincecum may insist on proceeding all the way to a hearing, where his case centered on the two Cy Youngs might carry the day.
Question of the Day
Which of these forces do you think is stronger: the norm of midpoint settlement, or the incentives created by the structure of baseball arbitration? Am I right about Lincecum’s salary figure, or are the Giants in fact closer? How likely is a deal at the midpoint ($10.5 million)?
Thank you for reading
This is a free article. If you enjoyed it, consider subscribing to Baseball Prospectus. Subscriptions support ongoing public baseball research and analysis in an increasingly proprietary environment.
Subscribe now
In either-or arbitration, there is an incentive to indicate that you will ask for some crazy number which will never be granted, in order to sucker your opponent into submitting a less reasonable number than they otherwise would have.
I suspect this is what happened in the Lincecum case. Rumors have been spreading of his agents' intention to submit 20+ million dollars, which seems to have caused the Giants to confidently lowball. That has left Lincecum's record high actual number as the more reasonable option, even if it's slightly on the high side.
In this case, I think the Giants settle closer to Lincecum's $13M, maybe $11.5-$12M.
Also, if 0 is the player figure, and 100 is the team figure, wouldn't an average settlement of 46% indicate that pre-arbitration settlements slightly favor the player?
The Priest-Klein hypothesis, which was originally developed to describe legal cases that proceed all the way to trial, basically tells us that we can't learn anything about the likelihood of one party or another to win based merely on the fact that it did in fact proceed all the way to trial. In the baseball arbitration context, the question is whether cases that proceed all the way to arbitration tend to favor (on the merits) players or teams. Because there are so few data points each year for this, it's a tough hypothesis to test. Nevertheless, my presumption is that the Priest-Klein hypothesis would apply, and that players and teams win arb. cases at about equal rates.
Now that I understand it, I wonder if there might be some risk tolerance considerations that would make it more likely for the player to win, because players would only be willing to go to arbitration if they thought they were likely to win. Teams might be willing to gamble a few hundred thousand dollars on an arbitrators decision, but for a player who may not have made big bucks up to this point that is probably a lot harder to do.
For instance, did both Tallet and Camp choose high numbers because they thought the Jays would go low but the team didn't do that? Consequently Tallet and Camp would have been reasonably sure they would lose in arbitration and were forced to settle around 20%.
And did the inverse occur in the one case >75%? That seems to be a likely path for Lincecum to follow as others above have noted. He could push the Giants all the way to arbitration. But if the Giants were to offer him $12m at this point I would be surprised for Lincecum to risk that much guaranteed for even a very small risk of getting stuck at $8m.
An arbitration question also: Could a team's (or player's) compromise offer be used in any way at arbitration? Since the arbitrators can't pick a mid-point salary, an arbitrator's knowledge that the team offered the player something very close to that mid-point might make it more likely the arbitrator would side with the team.
This tactic is increasingly popular (at least it seems like it is) and is a GREAT way teams can retain homegrown talent (DWright, ELongoria, etc.). It also skews the current FA market by taking a lot of the best players off it- meaning the resulting FA signings look worse than they would be if teams didn't work out multi-year deals with arb and pre-arb players.
(Great article BTW)
The Giants have already admitted they have almost nothing regarding Lincecum's performance to argue against him with. Even the Phillies had Howard hitting only .235 against southpaw in his season going into arbitration and 181 and 199 strikeouts.
Lincecum's performance has been eerily similar in all situations -- except when the margin is over four runs.
I can see it now:
Lincecum: How do back-to-back Cy Youngs look, especially since it hasn't ever been accomplished before in a pitcher's first three full seasons?
Sabean: We have looked carefully at Tim's record and have discovered that he's merely average when we are five or more runs ahead or behind. Tim's going to have to prove he can pitch in one-sided games before he can be considered a truly consistent pitcher.
In one-sided game we might as well have Barry Zito pitching. Oh, wait.
The lower the Giants went, the HIGHER Tim could afford to go.
IMO the Giants went low simply to give them more room in which to work a settlement with Tim. They don't want to go to a hearing. It's against their organizational philosophy.
If I were Tim, I would use the leverage of a likely arbitration win to forge a long-term contract. From the Giants' point of view, that becomes an iffy proposition -- especially with this year's ceiling capped at $13 million.
They have control over Tim for four seasons regardless. How about a four-year deal with three option years?
But by going low, the Giants eliminated any leverage they would have in settlement negotiations. Increasing the distance between their number and Lincecum's only decreases the likelihood of a settlement, since (a) a larger difference between reserve prices makes negotiation more difficult, and (b) it gives Lincecum less incentive to compromise, since he can probably win outright.
2. What if Lincecum just showed up to the hearing, plopped down his Cy Young awards on the desk in front of him, and stared at the arbiters the entire time? I wonder how that would impact the decision-making process...
What about when a player signs a multi-year deal with, different yearly rates, as often happens to avoid arbitration? The player will generally make below midpoint the first year of a multi-year deal, only to make more later, and so you have to be more specific about the settlement values. AAV can be misleading, too.
I don't see that bucket holding any water with a reasonable arbitrator, but maybe SF brass does.